Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 23, No. 8. (Oct., 1915), pp. 852-854. Book Review by: R. E. Freeman Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution. By THORSTEIN VEBLEN. New York: Macmillan, 1915. 8vo. pp. viii + 324. $1.50. --------------------------------------------------------------------------------- [852] The work is an application of Professor Veblen's well-known technological interpretation of history to the case of modern Germany. It is based on the fact that to each technological system there is attached a certain apparatus of convention and standard usage, and that, in evolution of society, the latter tends to persist, surviving the former, and living on into a new industrial system, opposing and shaping its development. In such a tendency, the author finds an explanation of the conflicting ideas of Great Britain and Germany and their different governmental organizations. Now the Germans and English are both of hybrid composition, the racial constituents being largely the same. This hybrid composition [853] gives a great facility in borrowing and "acts to hinder any given scheme or system from attaining a definitive stability." Thus England in early Tudor times borrowed a handicraft technology which was luckily stripped of the restrictive gild and charter regulations, the settled usages, routes, and methods that were then prevailing on the Continent. Aided, in addition, by her insularity and comparative immunity from war, England speedily developed the borrowed arts and crafts and led the way in the invention of labor-saving devices. The Continental technology fostered, on English soil, a spirit of individualism and democracy which encouraged the formulation of a philosophy of natural rights and an economic doctrine of freedom of competition. But unfortunately there grew up along with this a host of evil working conditions, an increasing obsolescence of technology, wasteful habits of living, costly amusements, armies of menials, and other unnecessary paraphernalia that impeded the increase of industrial efficiency. Germany, however, borrowed the modern mechanical processes without the individualistic philosophy and the other economic and cultural consequences. She received the technology of Britain into a feudal system where high industrial efficiency is wedded to a spirit of fealty and subservience. But as modern industry abhors national frontiers and local traits, the hegemony of Prussia among the German kingdoms was a condition essential to German industrial prosperity. So Prussia came with a militarism more vigorous and feudalistic than the other kingdoms and formed a dynastic state in the center of Europe. She immediately turned the wonderful technological efficiency of her citizens to her own ends, and, to overcome the prejudice of her people against personal servitude, changed fealty to a feudal monarch into subordination to a collective strength vested in a divinely appointed emperor. She instituted an imperial tariff policy, compulsory military service, and a government system of industrial tutelage; and by means of these developed a superior fighting machine. Such, in short, are the economic factors underlying the great ideals that antagonize one another on the battlefields of Europe: in England, individualism and democracy; in Germany, the spirit of subordination and the dynastic state. Around the German ideal of the state, fostered by imperial control of education and a sense of national efficiency and solidarity, there grew up a whole cultural scheme. The industrial revolution has not been able to exert its fullest cultural influence upon the German people, as it did in England, but eventually it will undermine the foundations of the dynastic state. So that "the movement for cultural reversion," for which the Germans strive today, "stands to gain [854] at least to the extent of a substantial, though presumably temporary, impairment and arrest of Western civilization at large." This explanation is one that goes to the roots of the national spirit - one that gives a place to both material and ideal factors. Professor Dewey's recent book deals with the philosophic basis of the German spirit and, taken in conjunction with the work of Professor Veblen, puts rich significance into the present war. "Every living thought represents a gesture made towards the world, an attitude taken to some practical situation in which we are implicated." If the reader has developed a taste for the author's characteristically cumbrous verbiage, he will find Imperial Germany and the Industrial Revolution excellent in every respect. R. E. FREEMAN UNIVERSITY OF CHICAGO