LABOUR'S FIRST BUDGET: reinforcing unequal Britain The political process in contemporary Britain seldom raises itself above the sound bites thought necessary to manipulate and deceive the public. The first Labour budget carefully followed this pattern. This budget, Chancellor Gordon Brown informed us, would `ensure Britain is equipped to rise to the challenge of the new and fast changing global economy'. It would do this, unlike previous budgets, without pursuing the short term interests of the few. His budget - a `people's budget for Britain's future' - would advance the long-term interests of the many. But, as DAVID YAFFE explains below, all this bluster is designed to conceal the harsh reality. Brown's Labour budget offers only contradictory proposals to tackle the economic problems facing Britain's parasitic and crisis-ridden economy while reinforcing inequality in an increasingly polarised class society. Labour's dilemma The Daily Mail was essentially right when it said, `Truly there is something Tory about this first Labour Budget for a generation.' Labour will continue with the attempt to build a competitive economy, like its Tory predecessors, through deregulated labour markets and cut-backs and privatisation of state welfare. Non-wage `labour' costs to capital will be reduced, forcing millions of working class people to face ever lower levels of social protection. The problem with this is that it will almost certainly place great strains on the coalition of forces which united to drive the Conservatives from power and elected Labour. In a recent article, David Marquand describes that coalition as encompassing `virtually the whole of the professional class, large swathes of corporate- sector management, what is left of the old, organised, upper-working-class Labour interest that the party came into existence to serve, and most of the ÒnewÓ Thatcherite working class that swung to the right in the late-1970s and early 1980s.' All these beneficiaries of the first Thatcher governments are not united by anything positive, but by fear of the political and social upheavals of a continuing neo-liberal offensive. They do not wish to reverse the process but to call a halt to it. But, as Marquand points out, this is not possible. The brutal logic of the global market-place entails `relentless and disruptive changes in virtually every sphere of social life'. His solution, however, is equally unrealisable. It is that Labour, which differs from Thatcherite Tories in accepting that Britain can only play a significant role in world affairs through close involvement in the European Union, should take a further step to embrace and defend the European social model from destruction at the hands of a rampant global capitalism (The Guardian 16 July 1997). Marquand does not understand why Blair's Labour Party is now in power and moreover acceptable to the ruling class. The representatives of British multinational capital are actually at the centre of Labour's coalition. They are there because, unlike the discredited and divided Tories, Labour is in a better position, as economic conditions deteriorate, to prevent an alliance against capitalism developing between the poor working class and sections of the middle class threatened with proletarianisation. Labour's dilemma is how to hold this coalition together in economic circumstances and with economic policies which must blow it apart. Hence the Budget speech rhetoric of urging `every business to play its part in a national crusade to equip this country for the future by taking on young unemployed men and women', while in reality attempting to force young people into dead-end jobs at poverty pay. Or the hollow call: ÔIt is time for the welfare state to put opportunity again into people's hands', while slashing social provision and removing basic social protection from millions of working class people. The Budget rhetoric soon recedes when confronted with the harsh reality of the British economy and Labour's economic and social policies for dealing with it. The real budget Public spending will be cut. In 1997/8 the control total will be £200m lower than under the Tory plans of November 1996 and unchanged from those for 1998/9. The budget deficit will be continually reduced throughout Labour's term of office and three different possible plans were outlined for doing this. The first allowed only a 0.75% growth in real spending a year for the three years from 1999/2000 (zero, if Labour's new higher forecast for inflation is used), leading to a fall in public spending to 36.7% of GDP in 2002, the lowest level since 1966. Other projections include rises in spending of 1.5% and 2.25% respectively. These will also bring public spending levels as a proportion of GDP below the levels of the last Tory government. Labour's plans for public spending are far harsher than the Tories achieved during their 18 years of power. The Institute of Fiscal Studies has estimated that if public spending had continued at the Tories's 18-year trend rate of growth, then it would be up to £35bn higher at the end of this parliament than under Labour. A great deal has been made of the £2.2bn extra spending taken from contingency reserves for increased spending on health and education. Last year the National Heath Service was left with a deficit of at least £350m. The extra £1.2bn found for 1998/9 represents a real growth of only 2.25% - less than the 3% average yearly growth attained over 18 years of Tory governments. This simply papers over the cracks. The baseline figure for NHS spending will not rise and the health service faces a 3% cut in its budget for 1999-2000. Spending on private health care has doubled from 5% to 10% of public health spending since 1979. Labour's present plans can only accelerate this process and leave millions of working class people without adequate health provision. The £1bn addition to the local authorities' education budget should prevent the sacking of about 12,000 teachers and stop the growth of class sizes of more than 30 spreading from primary into secondary schools. It budgets for a `modest' increase in teachers' pay. An extra £1.3bn from the windfall tax will begin to tackle the chronic neglect of school buildings, going some way towards the estimated £3.2bn backlog of repairs. For what is Labour's main priority area, this is hardly earth- shattering. Further increases in education and health spending would appear to come from funds drawn from the national lottery. All other government departments' and local authorities' expenditure is governed by Labour's rigid acceptance of previous Tory plans. Local authorities, faced with a real-term decrease in their budget, have warned the government that Ôunacceptable' cuts to fire, police, highways and environmental protection and consumer budgets will need to be made this year. Disciplining the poor £3.5bn from the one-off £5.2bn windfall tax on the excess profits of the privatised utilities will be used to finance the Labour's much-trumpeted `New Deal' Welfare to Work programme. This `New Deal' is more draconian than that proposed by the Tories. The young unemployed will be offered four options under the scheme: working for a private sector employer, receiving a £60 a week subsidy for six months; voluntary work; joining an environmental task force or going on a training course. All benefit will be cut from those who `unreasonably' refuse one of these options. Pregnant women, lone parents and those with long-term disabilities will lose up to 40% of their benefits if they refuse. A £75-a-week incentive will be given to employers who take on the long-term adult unemployed. Finally, lone parents who have not been in work will be `invited' by the employment service for a job interview and encouraged to find work and given help with childcare facilities. At the same time, no doubt as further `encouragement', Labour will go ahead with Tory plans to cut the one parent family benefit of £6.30 a week and the £5.20 paid to single parents on Income Support. A more detailed discussion of this programme appears elsewhere in this issue of FRFI. Its significance lies in Labour's determination to discipline and control the growing numbers of young people who increasingly reject and represent a potential threat to the social norms imposed by capitalist society. At the same time, drawing them into the workforce as cheap labour, even for short periods of time, serves the interests of capital, by pressurising the rest of the working class into accepting the ever worsening conditions at work at lower rates of pay. The lack of jobs for young people relates to the aggregate conditions of the economy not the lack of training and skills of young people. Capitalism cannot solve youth unemployment because it is no longer capable of creating sufficient long-term permanent jobs. Keeping the middle classes sweet The British economy is in the throes of an inflationary consumer boom. The housing market and the £35bn windfall payouts from building society flotations will fuel it further. Yet New Labour stood by its promises not to increase direct taxes on the middle classes. The small rise in consumer taxes through increased duties on petrol, alcohol and cigarettes, the cut in mortgage interest tax relief to 10 per cent and the rise in stamp duty on houses above £250,000 will lower consumer spending by a mere £2bn. On average this is equivalent to a 1p increase on income tax. Yet the middle classes are subsidised by some £10bn each year through tax incentives on pensions, PEPs and TESSAs - equivalent to 5p on income tax. They are the biggest beneficiaries from building society payouts. The budget not only did not reduce these subsidies but announced their continuation through individual savings accounts based on the principle of PEPs and TESSAs to be introduced in 1999. New Labour knows it must hold together the coalition that put it into power, while it puts into place the draconian measures needed to discipline and control the most impoverished sections of the working class. This political decision has economic consequences. While parts of the British economy are booming, large sections of manufacturing industry are stagnating. Unable to slow down the consumer boom by substantially higher taxes, Labour has to rely on a tighter monetary policy. The `independent' Bank of England is keen to oblige and has raised interest rates three times over the last three months with devastating consequences for manufacturing industry, as the pound surges and exports become less competitive. The pound has risen over 30% against the DM and 24% against a basket of currencies since last August. In May manufacturing output fell by 1.1% and engineering output by 2.3%, the biggest monthly decline since production was disrupted by freezing weather in 1987. The situation will deteriorate as more interest rate rises become necessary to curb the consumer boom. The real economy Since 1980, the Chancellor informed us, Britain has invested a lower share of GDP than most other industrialised countries. For every £100 invested per worker in Britain, Germany has invested over £140, The US and France around £150 and Japan over £160. He intends to change this by developing a tax system which encourages saving and which favours and rewards higher long term investment. So the main tax raising measure in the budget was the abolition of tax credits on advanced corporation tax (ACT) raising some £14bn over four years. Companies pay ACT when dividends are paid out. Shareholders get an equivalent credit and tax-exempt holders such as pension funds can claim repayment. Brown said he would abolish such credits because they encouraged companies to pay out dividends rather than reinvest profits. Yet the impact of this measure taking account of the 2% reduction in corporation tax was to increase taxation on the corporate sector by some £2bn a year. It is unlikely to encourage corporations and pensions to invest more in Britain. While investment in Britain is stagnating - investment as a proportion of GDP has fallen continuously during the current economic upswing with manufacturing investment almost 13% below its 1990 peak - British investment abroad is booming. In 1993, following the 1990-92 recession, British investment overseas (direct and portfolio) at £101.9bn, was greater than the total capital investment in Britain at £94.2bn and more than eight times the investment in manufacturing industry. In 1996 even after the recovery in domestic investment and following a fall in portfolio investment abroad, British overseas investment was equivalent to 77.9% of total capital investment in Britain and nearly six times that invested in manufacturing industry. Labour's budget offers no solution to Britain's economic problems. As economic conditions further deteriorate, and the economy stagnates, the Labour coalition will start to fall apart. For the first time in a number of years the opportunity will arise to build a new coalition of forces - a coalition which will have the impoverished working class at its core - this time against Labour and the capitalist system it fully supports. *